on their holdings. Most of the nation were restricted
to agriculture under conditions that spelt failure,
and imposed exile as the penalty for failure, since
other avenues to competence were closed. The
climax of misfortune was reached a generation after
the triumph of Free Trade. Ireland, being almost
wholly an agricultural country, suffered as a whole,
whereas England, an industrial country, suffered only
in districts, from the collapse of agricultural prices
in 1879. That catastrophe in rural life precipitated
Mr. Gladstone’s Land Law Act (Ireland), 1881.
Being precluded by his political tenets from protecting
Irish agriculture against foreign competition, or
assisting it with the resources of the State, Mr.
Gladstone aimed at alleviating the distress due to
the decadence of a national industry by defining with
meticulous nicety the respective shares which the
two parties engaged in agriculture—landlord
and tenant—were to derive from its dwindling
returns. He believed that the proportion of diminishing
profits due to the landlord, because of the inherent
capabilities of his property, and to the tenant, because
of his own and his predecessors’ exertions,
could be roughly determined by a few leading cases
in the Land Court; and, further, that landlords and
tenants throughout Ireland would conform to such guidance
as these decisions might afford. In this anticipation
he ignored the vital function of agriculture in Irish
life, and the effect which the growing stringency
of agricultural conditions would have on a population
that loved the land and rejoiced in litigation.
He created dual-ownership throughout Ireland, and
this led, as Lord Dufferin and other far-seeing statesmen
had foretold, to the land being starved of both capital
and industry. Irish agriculture was brought to
the brink of ruin. The misery of those involved
in that pass was exploited to engineer an attack on
the fabric of social order, and the lawlessness so
engendered was adduced as an argument for dissolving
the Union under which such tragedies could occur.
The leaders of the Conservative Party, when confronted
with this situation, determined that their duty, in
accordance with the spirit of the Act of Union, demanded
some use of the resources of a joint exchequer for
ministration to the peculiar needs of Ireland.
They decided that the credit of the State should be
employed to effect the abolition of dual-ownership
by converting the occupiers of Irish farms into owners
of the soil. Let it be granted that this policy
had been advocated by John Bright and enshrined in
the Land Law Acts of 1870 and 1881. It must be
added that these pious intentions remained a “dead
letter” until adequate machinery for giving them
effect was provided by the Land Purchase Acts, commonly
called the Ashbourne Acts, of 1885 and 1889.
The method pursued was as follows. Any individual
landlord could agree with any individual tenant on
the price which he would accept for the extinction