Proportional Representation Applied To Party Government eBook

This eBook from the Gutenberg Project consists of approximately 191 pages of information about Proportional Representation Applied To Party Government.

Proportional Representation Applied To Party Government eBook

This eBook from the Gutenberg Project consists of approximately 191 pages of information about Proportional Representation Applied To Party Government.
action would tend to conceal the true exact measure of favour in the first count.”  If this statement means anything it is that the three preferences which are required to be expressed should have been all counted as effective votes at the Hobart election instead of one only; and this is exactly what we advocate.  It is also admitted that when two candidates ran together at the first Launceston election the more popular candidate was defeated; and again the Argus correspondent writes of the recent Hobart election:—­“The defeat of Mr. Nicholls was doubtless due to the fact of his supporters’ over-confidence—­nothing else explains it.  Many people gave him No. 2 votes who would have given him No. 1 votes had they not felt assured of his success.”

A second reason why the wrong candidates are liable to be elected is that the process of elimination adopted by all the Hare methods has no mathematical justification.  The candidate who is first excluded has one preference only taken account of, while others have many preferences given effect to.  We have shown that this glaring injustice was recognized by Mr. Hare, and only adopted as a last resort.  Professor Nanson admits that “the process of elimination which has been adopted by all the exponents of Hare’s system is not satisfactory,” and adds—­“I do not know a scientific solution of the difficulty.”  To bring home the inequity of the process, consider a party which nominates six candidates, A, B, C, D, E, and F, and whose numbers entitle it to three seats, and suppose the electors to vote in the proportions and order shown below on the first count.

FIRST     SECOND    THIRD    FOURTH
COUNT.     COUNT.     COUNT.    COUNT.
7-vote     ADEFBC    ADEBC     AEBC     ABC
6-vote     EFDACB    EDACB     EACB     ACB
5-vote     CEBDFA    CEBDA     CEBA     CBA
4-vote     BDFACE    BDACE     BACE     BAC
4-vote     DCEFBA    DCEBA     CEBA     CBA
3-vote     FBAECD    BAECD     BAEC     BAC

It will be noted that F, having fewest first votes, is eliminated from the second count, D from the third count, and E from the fourth.  A has then 13 votes, B 7, and C 9.  If the quota be 9 votes, A’s surplus would be passed on to B, and A, B, and C would be declared elected.  But D, E, and F are the candidates most in general favour, and ought to have been elected.  For if any one of the rejected candidates be compared with any one of the successful candidates it will be found that in every case the rejected candidate is higher in order of favour on a majority of the papers.  Again, if the Block Vote be applied, by counting three effective votes, the result would be—­A 10 votes, B 12, C 9, D 21, E 22, and F 13.  D, E, and F would therefore be elected.  Thus we see that A, B, and C, the favourites of sections within the party, are elected, and D, E, and F, the candidates most in general favour—­those who represent a compromise among the sections—­are rejected.

Copyrights
Project Gutenberg
Proportional Representation Applied To Party Government from Project Gutenberg. Public domain.