the support of one of the two national parties, but
which in spite of that support has so far made little
substantial progress. Civil service reform, on
the other hand, was the first agitation looking in
the direction of political purification. The early
reformers believed that the eradication of the spoils
system would deal a deadly blow at political corruption
and professional politics. But although they
have been fairly successful in establishing the “merit”
system in the various public offices, the results of
the reform have not equaled the promises of its advocates.
While it is still an important part of the programme
of reform from the point of view of many reformers,
it has recently been over-shadowed by other issues.
It does not provoke either as much interest as it
did or as much opposition. Municipal reform has,
of course, almost as many centers of agitation as
there are centers of corruption—that is,
large municipalities in the United States. It
began as a series of local non-partisan movements for
the enforcement of the laws, the dispossession of the
“rascals,” and the businesslike, efficient
administration of municipal affairs; but the reformers
discovered in many cases that municipal corruption
could not be eradicated without the reform of state
politics, and without some drastic purging of the
local public service corporations. They have
consequently in many cases enlarged the area of their
agitation; but in so doing they have become divided
among themselves, and their agitation has usually
lost its non-partisan character. Finally the agitation
against the trusts has developed a confused hodge-podge
of harmless and deadly, overlapping and mutually exclusive,
remedies, which are the cause of endless disagreements.
Of course they are all for the People and against
the Octopus, but beyond this precise and comprehensive
statement of the issue, the reformers have endlessly
different views about the nature of the disease and
the severity of the necessary remedy.
If reform is an ambiguous and many-headed thing, the
leading reformers are as far as possible from being
a body of men capable of mutual cooeperation.
They differ almost as widely among themselves as they
do from the beneficiaries or supporters of the existing
abuses. William R. Hearst, William Travers Jerome,
Seth Low, and George B. McClellan are all in their
different ways reformers; but they would not constitute
precisely a happy family. Indeed, Mr. Hearst,
who in his own opinion is the only immaculate reformer,
is, in the eyes of his fellow-reformers, as dangerous
a public enemy as the most corrupt politician or the
most unscrupulous millionaire. Any reformer who,
like Mr. William Jennings Bryan, proclaims views which
are in some respects more than usually radical, comes
in for heartier denunciation from his brothers in reform
than he does from the conservatives. Each of our
leading reformers is more or less a man on horseback,
who is seeking to popularize a particular brand of