agricultural progress began with the emancipation of
the serfs, and increased productivity was everywhere
the immediate result of improvements in the method
of culture. Thus the poor light soils of Germany,
France, and Holland have been made to produce more
than the vaunted “black earth” of Russia.
And from these ameliorations the land-owning class
has everywhere derived the chief advantages. Are
not the landed proprietors of England—the
country in which serfage was first abolished—the
richest in the world? And is not the proprietor
of a few hundred morgen in Germany often richer than
the Russian noble who has thousands of dessyatins?
By these and similar plausible arguments the Press
endeavoured to prove to the proprietors that they ought,
even in their own interest, to undertake the emancipation
of the serfs. Many proprietors, however, showed
little faith in the abstract principles of political
economy and the vague teachings of history as interpreted
by the contemporary periodical literature. They
could not always refute the ingenious arguments adduced
by the men of more sanguine temperament, but they
felt convinced that their prospects were not nearly
so bright as these men represented them to be.
They believed that Russia was a peculiar country,
and the Russians a peculiar people. The lower
classes in England, France, Holland, and Germany were
well known to be laborious and enterprising, while
the Russian peasant was notoriously lazy, and would
certainly, if left to himself, not do more work than
was absolutely necessary to keep him from starving.
Free labour might be more profitable than serfage
in countries where the upper classes possessed traditional
practical knowledge and abundance of capital, but
in Russia the proprietors had neither the practical
knowledge nor the ready money necessary to make the
proposed ameliorations in the system of agriculture.
To all this it was added that a system of emancipation
by which the peasants should receive land and be made
completely independent of the landed proprietors had
nowhere been tried on such a large scale.
There were thus two diametrically opposite opinions
regarding the economic results of the abolition of
serfage, and we have now to examine which of these
two opinions has been confirmed by experience.
Let us look at the question first from the point of
view of the land-owners.
The reader who has never attempted to make investigations
of this kind may naturally imagine that the question
can be easily decided by simply consulting a large
number of individual proprietors, and drawing a general
conclusion from their evidence. In reality I found
the task much more difficult. After roaming about
the country for five years (1870-75), collecting information
from the best available sources, I hesitated to draw
any sweeping conclusions, and my state of mind at that
time was naturally reflected in the early editions
of this work. As a rule the proprietors could