following passage from Dr. Cunningham’s Growth
of English Industry and Commerce correctly represents
the attitude of the Church towards commerce at the
end of the Middle Ages: ’The ecclesiastic
who regarded the merchant as exposed to temptations
in all his dealings would not condemn him as sinful
unless it were clear that a transaction were entered
on solely for greed, and hence it was the tendency
for moralists to draw additional distinctions, and
refuse to pronounce against business practices where
common sense did not give the benefit of the doubt.’[2]
We have seen that one motive which would justify the
carrying on of trade was the desire to support one’s
self and one’s family. Of course this motive
was capable of bearing a very extended and elastic
interpretation, and would justify increased commercial
profits according as the standard of life improved.
The other motive given by the theologians, namely,
the benefit of the State, was also one which was capable
of a very wide construction. One must remember
that even the manual labourer was bound not to labour
solely for avaricious gain, but also for the benefit
of his fellow-men. ’It is not only to chastise
our bodies,’ says Basil, ’it is also by
the love of our neighbour that the labourer’s
life is useful so that God may furnish through us
our weaker brethren’;[3] and a fifteenth-century
book on morality says: ’Man should labour
for the honour of God. He should labour in order
to gain for himself and his family the necessaries
of life and what will contribute to Christian joy,
and moreover to assist the poor and the sick by his
labours. He who acting otherwise seeks only the
pecuniary recompense of his work does ill, and his
labours are but usury. In the words of St. Augustine,
“thou shalt not commit usury with the work of
thy hands, for thus wilt thou lose thy soul,"’[4]
The necessity for altruism and regard for the needs
of one’s neighbour as well as of one’s
self were therefore motives necessary to justify labour
as well as commerce; and it would be wrong to conclude
that the teaching of the scholastics on the necessity
for a good motive to justify trade operated to damp
individual enterprise, or to discourage those who were
inclined to launch commercial undertakings, any more
than the insistence on the need for a similar motive
in labourers was productive of idleness. What
the mediaeval teaching on commerce really amounted
to was that, while commerce was as legitimate as any
other occupation, owing to the numerous temptations
to avarice and dishonesty which it involved, it must
be carefully scrutinised and kept within due bounds.
It was more difficult to insure the observance of
the just price in the case of a sale by a merchant
than in one by an artificer; and the power which the
merchant possessed of raising the price of the necessaries
of life on the poor by engrossing and speculation
rendered him a person whose operations should be carefully
controlled.
[Footnote 1: Cunningham, Growth of English Industry and Commerce, vol. i. p. 255.]