he may have incurred, and will enable him to provide
for his needs, spiritual and temporal.[3] It was not
until the sixteenth century that the fixing of the
just price of wages was submitted to scientific discussion;[4]
in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries there is
little to be found bearing on this subject except
the passage of Langenstein which we have quoted, and
some strong exhortations by Antoninus of Florence to
masters to pay good wages.[5] The reason for this
paucity of authority upon a subject of so much importance
is that in practice the machinery provided by the
guilds had the effect of preserving a substantially
just remuneration to the artisan. When a man
is in perfect health he does not bother to read medical
books. In the same way, the proper remuneration
of labour was so universally recognised as a duty,
and so satisfactorily enforced, that it seems to have
been taken for granted, and therefore passed over,
by the writers of the period. One may agree with
Brants in concluding that, ’the principle of
just price in sales was applied to wages; fluctuations
in wages were not allowed; the just price, as in sales,
rested on the approximate equality of the services
rendered; and that this equality was estimated by common
opinion.’[6] Of course, in the case of slave
labour it could not be said that any wage was paid.
The master was entitled to the services of the slave,
and in return was bound to furnish him with the necessaries
of life.[7]
[Footnote 1: Op. cit., p. 103.]
[Footnote 2: An excellent bibliography of books
dealing with the history of the working classes in
the Middle Ages is to be found in Brants, op. cit.,
p. 105. The need for examining concrete economic
phenomena is insisted on in Ryan’s Living
Wage, p. 28.]
[Footnote 3: De Cont. We have here a recognition
of the principle that the value of labour is not to
be measured by anything extrinsic to itself, e.g.
by the value of the product, but by its own natural
function and end, and this function and end is the
supplying of the requirements of human life.
The wage must, therefore, be capable of supplying
the same needs that the expenditure of a labourer’s
energy is meant to supply. (See Cronin, Ethics,
vol. ii. p. 390.)]
[Footnote 4: Brants, op. cit., p. 118.]
[Footnote 5: The passages from the Summa
of Antoninus bearing on the subject are reprinted
in Brants, op. cit., p. 120.]
[Footnote 6: Op. cit., p. 125.]
[Footnote 7: Brants, op. cit., p. 116,
quoting Le Lime du Tresor of Brunetto Latini.]
Sec. 5. Value of the Conception of the Just Price.