life and regulation of inter-municipal commerce, and
introduced marked contrasts to the conditions of business
in ancient cities. The Christian appreciation
of the duty of work rendered the lot of the mediaeval
villain a very different thing from that of the slave
of the ancient empire. The responsibility of
proprietors, like the responsibility of prices, was
so far insisted on as to place substantial checks
on tyranny of every kind. For these principles
were not mere pious opinions, but effective maxims
in practical life. Owing to the circumstances
in which the vestiges of Roman civilisation were locally
maintained, and the foundations of the new society
were laid, there was ample opportunity for Christian
teaching and example to have a marked influence on
its development.’[5] In Dr. Cunningham’s
book entitled Politics and Economics the same
opinion is expressed:[6] ’Religious and industrial
life were closely interconnected, and there were countless
points at which the principles of divine law must
have been brought to bear on the transaction of business,
altogether apart from any formal tribunal. Nor
must we forget the opportunities which directors had
for influencing the conduct of penitents....
Partly through the operation of the royal power, partly
through the decisions of ecclesiastical authorities,
but more generally through the influence of a Christian
public opinion which had been gradually created, the
whole industrial organism took its shape, and the
acknowledged economic principles were framed.’
We have quoted these passages from Dr. Cunningham’s
works at length because they are of great value in
helping us to estimate the rival parts played by theory
and practice in mediaeval economic teaching; in the
first place, because the author was by no means prepossessed
in favour of the teaching of the canonists, but rather
unsympathetic to it; in the second place, because,
although his work was concerned primarily with practice,
he found himself obliged to make a study of theory
before he could properly understand the practice;
and lastly, because they point particularly to the
effect of the teaching on just price. When we
come to speak of this part of the subject we shall
find that Dr. Cunningham failed to appreciate the
true significance of the canonist doctrine. If
an eminent author, who does not quite appreciate the
full import of this doctrine, and who is to some extent
contemptuous of its practical value, nevertheless
asserts that it exercised an all-powerful influence
on the practice of the age in which it was preached,
we are surely justified in asserting that the study
of theory may be profitably pursued without a preliminary
history of the contemporary practice.
[Footnote 1: Even Endemann warns his readers against assuming that the canonist teaching had no influence on everyday life. (Studien, vol. ii. p. 404.)]
[Footnote 2: Ashley, op. cit., vol. i. pt. ii. pp. 383-85. Again: ‘The later canonist dialectic was the midwife of modern economics’ (ibid., p. 397).]