century upon this weighty question; but we know enough
to affirm that the monetary doctrine was very developed
and very far-seeing.’[1] Buridan analysed the
different functions and utilities of money, and explained
the different ways in which its value might be changed.[2]
He did not, however, proceed to discuss the much more
important question as to when the sovereign was entitled
to make these alterations. This was reserved for
Nicholas Oresme, who published his famous treatise
about the year 1373. The merits of this work
have excited the unanimous admiration of all who have
studied it. Roscher says that it contains ’a
theory of money, elaborated in the fourteenth century,
which remains perfectly correct to-day, under the
test of the principles applied in the nineteenth century,
and that with a brevity, a precision, a clarity, and
a simplicity of language which is a striking proof
of the superior genius of its author.’[3] According
to Brants, ’the treatise of Oresme is one of
the first to be devoted ex professo to an economic
subject, and it expresses many ideas which are very
just, more just than those which held the field for
a long period after him, under the name of mercantilism,
and more just than those which allowed of the reduction
of money as if it were nothing more than a counter
of exchange.’[4] ’Oresme’s treatise
on money,’ says Macleod, ’may be justly
said to stand at the head of modern economic literature.
This treatise laid the foundations of monetary science,
which are now accepted by all sound economists.’[5]
’Oresme’s completely secular and naturalistic
method of treating one of the most important problems
of political economy,’ says Espinas, ’is
a signal of the approaching end of the Middle Ages
and the dawn of the Renaissance.’[6] Dr. Cunningham
adds his tribute of praise: ’The conceptions
of national wealth and national power were ruling ideas
in economic matters for several centuries, and Oresme
appears to be the earliest of the economic writers
by whom they were explicitly adopted as the very basis
of his argument.... A large number of points
of economic doctrine in regard to coinage are discussed
with much judgment and clearness.’[7] Endemann
alone is[8] inclined to quarrel with the pre-eminence
of Oresme; but on this question, he is in a minority
of one.[9]
[Footnote 1: Op. cit., p. 186.]
[Footnote 2: Quaest. super Lib. Eth., v. 17; Quaest. super Lib. Pol., i. 11.]
[Footnote 3: Quoted in Wolowski, op. cit., and see Roscher, Geschichte, p. 25.]
[Footnote 4: Op. cit., p. 190.]
[Footnote 5: History of Economics, p. 37.]
[Footnote 6: Op. cit., p. 110.]
[Footnote 7: Growth of English Industry and Commerce, vol. i. p. 359.]
[Footnote 8: Grundsaetze, p. 75.]
[Footnote 9: See an interesting note in Brants, op. cit., p. 187.]