of this important proviso. Gold as currency was
so convenient and perfect that its perfection has been
improved upon by this ingenious device, which prevented
its actually passing from hand to hand as currency,
and substituted for it an enormous mass of pieces
of paper which were promises to pay it, if ever the
holders of the paper chose to exercise their power
to demand it. By this method gold has been enabled
to circulate in the form of paper substitutes to an
extent which its actual amount would have made altogether
impossible if it had had to do its circulation, so
to speak, in its own person. From the application
of this great economy to gold two consequences have
followed; the first is that the effectiveness of gold
as a standard of value has been weakened because this
power that banks have given to it of circulating by
substitute has obviously depreciated its value by
enormously multiplying the effective supply of it.
Depreciation in the buying power of money, and a consequent
rise in prices, has consequently been a factor which
has been almost constantly at work for centuries with
occasional reactions, during which the process went
the other way. Another consequence has been that
people, seeing the ease with which pieces of paper
can be multiplied, representing a right to gold which
is only in exceptional cases exercised, have proceeded
to ask whether there is really any necessity to have
gold behind the paper at all, and whether it would
not be possible to evolve some ideal form of super-paper
which could take the place of gold as the basis of
the ordinary paper which is created by the machinery
of credit, which would be made exchangeable into it
on demand instead of into gold.
It is difficult to say how far the events of the war
have contributed to the agitation for the substitution
for gold of some other form of international currency.
It would seem at first sight that the position of
gold at the centre of the credit system has been shaken
owing to the fact that in Sweden and some other neutral
countries the obligation to receive gold in payment
for goods has been for the time being abrogated.
The critics of the gold standard are thus enabled
to say, “See what has happened to your theory
of the universal acceptability of gold. Here
are countries which refuse to accept any more gold
in payment for goods. They say, ’We do not
want your gold any more. We want something that
we can eat or make into clothes to put on our backs.’”
This is certainly an extremely curious development
that is one of the by-products of war’s economic
lessons. But I do not feel quite sure that it
has really taught us anything new. All that has
ever been claimed for gold is that it is universally
acceptable when men are buying and selling together
under more or less normal circumstances. It has
always been recognised that a shipwrecked crew on
a desert island would be unlikely to exchange the coco-nuts
or fish or any other commodities likely to sustain
life which they could find, for any gold which happened
to be in the possession of any of them, except with
a view to their being possibly picked up by a passing
ship, and returning to conditions under which gold
would reassume its old privilege of acceptability.