in shops and factories. It is obvious that such
competition reduced the field of free labour, when
it did not close it entirely, and the free labour
must have been unduly cheapened. But to suppose
that all the Roman work, whether in town or country,
was done by slaves is to be grossly in the wrong.
Romans were to be found acting as ploughmen and herdsmen,
workers in vineyards, carpenters, masons, potters,
shoemakers, tanners, bakers, butchers, fullers, metal-workers,
glass-workers, clothiers, greengrocers, shopkeepers
of all kinds. There were Roman porters, carters,
and wharf-labourers, as well as Roman confectioners
and sausage-sellers. To these private occupations
must be added many positions in the lower public or
civil service. There was, for example, abundant
call for attendants of the magistrates, criers, messengers,
and clerks. Unfortunately our information concerning
all this class is very inadequate. The Roman
writers—historians, philosophers, rhetoricians,
and poets—have extremely little to say about
the humble persons who apparently did nothing to make
history or thought. They are mentioned but incidentally,
and generally without interest, if not with some contempt,
except where a poet is choosing to glorify the simple
life and therefore turns his gaze on the frugal peasantry,
who doubtless did, in sober fact, retain most of the
sturdy old Roman spirit. About the soldiers we
know much, and not a little about the schoolmasters.
The connection of the one occupation with history and
of the other with authors will account for this fact.
Something will be said of the army and also of the
schools in their special places. Keepers of inns
are not rarely in evidence in the literature of satire
and epigram, and no language seems too contemptuous
for their alleged dishonesty. But of inns enough
has been said. We learn that the booksellers
made money out of the works of which they caused their
slaves to make copies, and which they sold in “well
got up” style for four shillings, or, in the
case of slender volumes, for as little as fourpence-halfpenny.
But to this day we do not know how much profit an
author drew from the bookseller, or how it was determined,
or whether he drew any at all. It is most reasonable
to suppose that he sold a book straight out to the
publisher for what he could get. Otherwise it
is hard to see how any check could be kept upon the
sales. The only occupation upon which literature
offers us systematic information is agriculture, including
the pasturing of cattle and the culture of the vine.
For the rest we derive more knowledge from the excavations
of Pompeii than from any other source. From actual
shops and their contents, from pictures illustrating
contemporary life, and from inscriptions and advertisements,
we are enabled to reconstruct some picture of commercial
and industrial operations. We can see the fuller,
the baker, the goldsmith, the wine-seller, and the
wreath-maker at their work. We can discern something
of the retail trade in the Forum; or we can see the
auctioneer making up his accounts.