The limited amount became a prize to be contended
for. Land in the interior offered itself at less
than one dollar an acre. Land on the seaboard
had been raised to fifty dollars per acre, and labor,
forced to elect between them, took the cheaper.
The heirs who came to an estate, or the men of capital
who retired from business, sought a location in the
West. Lands on the seaboard were forced to seek
for purchasers; purchasers came to the seaboard to
seek for slaves. Their prices were elevated to
their value not upon the seaboard where lands were
capital but in the interior where the interest upon
the cost of labor was the only charge upon production.
Labor therefore ceased to be profitable in the one
place as it became profitable in the other. Estates
which were wealth to their original proprietors became
a charge to the descendants who endeavored to maintain
them. Neglect soon came to the relief of unprofitable
care; decay followed neglect. Mansions became
tenantless and roofless. Trees spring in their
deserted halls and wave their branches through dismantled
windows. Drains filled up; the swamps returned.
Parish churches in imposing styles of architecture
and once attended by a goodly company in costly equipages,
are now abandoned. Lands which had ready sale
at fifty dollars per acre now sell for less than five
dollars; and over all these structures of wealth,
with their offices of art, and over these scenes of
festivity and devotion, there now hangs the pall of
an unalterable gloom."[79] In a later essay the same
writer dealt with developments in the ’fifties
in more sober phrases which are corroborated by the
census returns. Within the decade, he said, as
many as ten thousand slaves had been drawn from Charleston
by the attractive prices of the west, and the towns
of the interior had suffered losses in the same way.
The slaves had been taken in large numbers from all
manufacturing employments, and were now being sold
by thousands each year from the rice fields. “They
are as yet retained by cotton and the culture incident
to cotton; but as almost every negro offered in our
markets is bid for by the West, the drain is likely
to continue.” In the towns alone was the
loss offset in any degree by an inflow of immigration.[80]
[Footnote 79: L.W. Spratt, The Foreign
Slave Trade, the source of political power, of material
progress, of social integrity and of social emancipation
to the South (Charleston, 1858), pp. 7, 8.]
[Footnote 80: L.W. Spratt, “Letter
to John Perkins of Louisiana,” in the Charleston
Mercury, Feb. 13, 1861.]
A similar trend as to slaves but with a sharply contrasting
effect upon prosperity was described by Gratz Brown
as prevailing in Missouri. The slave population,
said he, is in process of rapid decline except in a
dozen central counties along the Missouri River.
“Hemp is the only staple here left that will
pay for investment in negroes,” and that can
hardly hold them against the call of the cotton belt.