and boundaries, so plans of the land thus sold were
made on tablets of bronze, and kept by the State.
[Sidenote: Occupation.] 3. She allowed private
persons to ‘occupy’ it on payment of ‘vectigal,’
or a portion of the produce; and, though not surrendering
the title to the land, permitted the possessors to
use it as their private property for purchase, sale,
and succession. [Sidenote: Commons.] 4. A
portion was kept as common pasture land for those
to whom the land had been given or sold, or by whom
it was occupied and those who used it paid ‘scriptura,’
or a tax of so much per head on the beasts, for whose
grazing they sent in a return. This irregular
system was fruitful in evil. It suited the patres
with whom it originated, for they were for a time
the sole gainers by it. Without money it must
have been hopeless to occupy tracts distant from Rome.
The poor man who did so would either involve himself
in debt, or be at the mercy of his richer neighbours,
whose flocks would overrun his fields, or who might
oust him altogether from them by force, and even seize
him himself and enroll him as a slave. The rich
man, on the other hand, could use such land for pasture,
and leave the care of his flocks and herds to clients
and slaves. [Sidenote: This irregular system the
germ of latifundia.] So originated those ‘latifundia,’
or large farms, which greatly contributed to the ruin
of Rome and Italy. The tilled land grew less
and with it dwindled the free population and the recruiting
field for the army. Gangs of slaves became more
numerous, and were treated with increased brutality;
and as men who do not work for their own money are
more profuse in spending it than those who do, the
extravagance of the Roman possessors helped to swell
the tide of luxury, which rose steadily with foreign
conquest, and to create in the capital a class free
in name indeed, but more degraded, if less miserable,
than the very slaves, who were treated like beasts
through Italy. It is not certain whether anyone
except a patrician could claim ‘occupation’
as a right; but, as the possessors could in any case
sell the land to plebeians, it fell into the hands
of rich men, to whichever class they belonged, both
at Rome, and in the Roman colonies, and the Municipia;
and as it was never really their property—’dominium’—but
the property of the State, it was a constant source
of envy and discontent among the poor.
[Sidenote: Why complaints about the Public Land became louder at the close of the second century B.C.] As long as fresh assignations of land and the plantations of colonies went on, this discontent could be kept within bounds. But for a quarter of a century preceding our period scarcely any fresh acquisitions of land had been made in Italy, and, with no hope of new allotments from the territory of their neighbours, the people began to clamour for the restitution of their own. [Sidenote: Previous agrarian legislation. Spurius Cassius.] The first attempt to wrest public