great man had inwardly projected for his great work,
has not been handed down to us and may be conceived
of very variously, yet he was beyond doubt aware of
what he was doing. Little as the intention of
usurping monarchical power can be mistaken, as little
will those who survey the whole circumstances on this
account blame Gracchus. An absolute monarchy
is a great misfortune for a nation, but it is a less
misfortune than an absolute oligarchy; and history
cannot censure one who imposes on a nation the lesser
suffering instead of the greater, least of all in
the case of a nature so vehemently earnest and so
far aloof from all that is vulgar as was that of Gaius
Gracchus. Nevertheless it may not conceal the
fact that his whole legislation was pervaded in a
most pernicious way by conflicting aims; for on the
one hand it aimed at the public good, while on the
other hand it ministered to the personal objects and
in fact the personal vengeance of the ruler.
Gracchus earnestly laboured to find a remedy for
social evils, and to check the spread of pauperism;
yet he at the same time intentionally reared up a
street proletariate of the worst kind in the capital
by his distributions of corn, which were designed
to be, and became, a premium to all the lazy and hungry
civic rabble. Gracchus censured in the bitterest
terms the venality of the senate, and in particular
laid bare with unsparing and just severity the scandalous
traffic which Manius Aquillius had driven with the
provinces of Asia Minor;(25) yet it was through the
efforts of the same man that the sovereign populace
of the capital got itself alimented, in return for
its cares of government, by the body of its subjects.
Gracchus warmly disapproved the disgraceful spoliation
of the provinces, and not only instituted proceedings
of wholesome severity in particular cases, but also
procured the abolition of the thoroughly insufficient
senatorial courts, before which even Scipio Aemilianus
had vainly staked his whole influence to bring the
most decided criminals to punishment. Yet he
at the same time, by the introduction of courts composed
of merchants, surrendered the provincials with their
hands fettered to the party of material interests,
and thereby to a despotism still more unscrupulous
than that of the aristocracy had been; and he introduced
into Asia a taxation, compared with which even the
form of taxation current after the Carthaginian model
in Sicily might be called mild and humane—
just because on the one hand he needed the party of
moneyed men, and on the other hand required new and
comprehensive resources to meet his distributions
of grain and the other burdens newly imposed on the
finances. Gracchus beyond doubt desired a firm
administration and a well-regulated dispensing of
justice, as numerous thoroughly judicious ordinances
testify; yet his new system of administration rested
on a continuous series of individual usurpations only
formally legalized, and he intentionally drew the